Literature
Understanding When an Increase in Money Supply Causes Inflation
Understanding When an Increase in Money Supply Causes Inflation
When does an escalation in the money supply trigger inflation, and when does it not? The answer often revolves around the relationship between the money supply and the economic growth rate. In this article, we will explore this question, along with the complexities of the money creation process and the role of central banks in managing economic cycles.
The Link Between Money Supply and Inflation
In general, an increase in the money supply beyond the economic growth rate tends to cause inflation. For example, if GDP growth is 4% and the money supply is also expanding at 4%, the additional liquidity is unlikely to result in significant price increases.
The chart below illustrates the U.S. money supply growth since 2020. An astonishing 47% increase in the money supply has been observed. This growth is not entirely unexpected, given historical trends and economic theory. However, the question arises: when does this extra money lead to inflation?
[img]
Understanding the Two Definitions of 'Money Supply'
When the concept of inflation and the money supply is discussed, there are typically two 'definitions' that come into play: the technical definitions like M0, M1, M2, or M3, and the popular notion of 'money printed by THE FEDTM or THE GOVERNMENTTM.' Here, the popular misunderstanding often pertains to the 'money supply' as perceived by the public, focusing on the actions of central banks like the Federal Reserve (the Fed).
The actual question we need to address is: 'When the Federal Reserve System pumps money into the economy, are there specific conditions under which such action causes inflation?' The answer is nuanced, depending on the economic context and expectations.
The Role of the Federal Reserve
The Federal Reserve steps in to manage economic cycles. When economic growth is slowing, the Fed may increase the money supply to stimulate the economy. Conversely, when growth is surging, the Fed may reduce the money supply to prevent overheating. These actions help manage inflation, but they do not guarantee that no inflation will occur.
There are exceptions where the Fed may need to target higher interest rates or decrease money supply beyond the economic cycle to combat inflation expectations. For example, during the 1970s and in 2023, high inflation expectations may necessitate stricter monetary policy.
Understanding the Money Creation Process
The money supply creation process is not solely controlled by central banks. Regular banks play a significant role in this process through fractional reserve banking. For instance, if you and nine others each deposit $10,000, the bank can lend out $60,000, effectively doubling the money supply.
The reverse is also true. If you withdraw your $10,000, the bank might reduce the loan by $60,000 to $55,000, decreasing the money supply. However, in reality, the system is more complex, with a continuous cycle of lending and borrowing.
Booms, Busts, and Central Banking
Economic booms can exacerbate inflation, especially if there is irrational exuberance in loan making. Central banks step in to control this by increasing interest rates to discourage excessive borrowing and lending. During economic busts, the money supply can contract dramatically as banks tighten lending conditions. Central banks then step in to provide liquidity and stabilize the economy.
During economic crises, as seen in 2008, the Fed expands the money supply through unconventional measures like purchasing treasury bonds. This action injects liquidity into the financial system and prevents deflationary traps. Similarly, the Treasury plays a crucial role in stabilizing the economy.
Conditions Under Which Extra Money Supply Causes Inflation
In many cases, extra money supply does not cause inflation if the private sector (banks, individuals, and companies) is already regulating its own money supply. A reduction in private sector borrowing can lead to a rapid decrease in the money supply, creating a deflationary trap. In such scenarios, central banks can pump money into the economy without triggering inflation.
However, when the private sector is actively generating new money through loans, adding more money from the central bank can lead to an imbalance where the supply exceeds demand, causing inflation.
Understanding these dynamics is crucial for both economic policymakers and the general public. It highlights the intricate relationship between monetary policy, economic cycles, and inflation expectations.